Price War

Bertrand Competition

Bertrand Competition is a basic micro-economic model in which all firms set their own price, with each firm assuming the other competitors in the market will not change price.

Bertrand Competition can be contrasted with Cournot Competition in which firms first determine their own output capacity, then set price. See also the Market Simulation: MS-182 Cournot Competition.

Joseph Bertrand developed the Bertrand Competition Model in 1883. He argued that, because firms always have an incentive to cut price, the market will inevitably reach a point where all prices are reduced down to marginal cost, and all profitability is eliminated. Hence, Bertrand Competition is often associated with vicious “race to the bottom” Price Wars.

This version of the Bertrand Competition Model depends upon some specific assumptions:

  1. There are at least two Competitors in the Market;
  2. The Competitors cannot cooperate in any way;
  3. Each Competitor sells the exact same Commodity Product;
  4. Each Competitor can supply enough of the Product to satisfy the entire Market by itself;
  5. All Customers have perfect knowledge of all Products and Prices in the Market;
  6. Customers all have the same access to the Market (shipping costs are constant); and
  7. Customers want to buy everything from the Competitor with the lowest Price.

Variations to this Bertrand Competition Model are explored in follow-on Market Simulations (find links at the bottom of this page). These variations relax the assumptions listed above, with the result that Competitors can set profitable prices.

This Case Study provides a high-level overview of the workflow without detailed explanation. It assumes you are already somewhat familiar with KNIME and Market Simulation. If not, start by reviewing the Building Blocks and Community Nodes.

Step #1: Setup Competitors

Bertrand Competition requires at least two Competitors in the Market (otherwise a Monopoly Market would be the suitable model). Our two Competitors are:

  1. Spacely Sprockets
  2. Cogswell Cogs

Both Competitors sell an undifferentiated “Sprockets” Product.

A Product Generator node is used to define the Market comprising of these two Competitors. The Product that both Competitors offer has the single Feature ‘Sprockets’.

The Willingness To Pay (WTP) that Customers have for Sprockets is determined by the Customer Distributions node. In this case, Customers have a Mean WTP of $100 with a Standard Deviation (SD) of $50.

The Customer Distributions node also sets the Number of Customers in the Market to be 10,000. Each Customer in the Market is given an identification number, ranging from C00001 to C10000. A row-by-row comparison of the ‘Output WTP Matrix’ from the Product Generator node shows that each Customer considers both Products to be identical in value.

Product Features

Willingness To Pay (WTP)

WTP Matrix

Step 2: Setup Pricing Loop

The Prices for both Competitors are set using ‘Flow Variables’. These Flow Variables can be used and modified by all the nodes in the Pricing Loop, so it is possible to run Price Experiments on several Prices and then select those Prices that yields the best result.

The most important Flow Variables are:

  • Spacely_Price
  • Cogswell_Price

The Bertrand Model will start with the initial Price of $150 for both Products. Each Loop Iteration will then adjust the Prices depending upon the expectations of both Spacely and Cogswell. Remember, both Competitors will change Price assuming that the other Competitor retains their old Price.

Additional Flow Variables are provided for Cost:

  • Spacely_Cost
  • Cogswell_Cost

These Cost Flow Variables are not used by the Pricing Loop but are provided for the benefit of the user (in case you want to experiment with how a Cost change could alter the results).

The ‘Price_Change_Percentage’ Flow Variable sets the size of the Price increase or decrease.

Starting Variables

Converted into Flow Variables

Step 3: Price Experiments

Five Price Experiments are run simultaneously:

  1. Raise Spacely’s Price
  2. Lower Spacely’s Price
  3. No Price Change for either Product
  4. Raise Cogswell’s Price
  5. Lower Cogswell’s Price

As both Competitors expect the other to retain their old Price, there is no need to experiment with adjusting both Prices simultaneously.

The ‘Java Snippet’ nodes are used to change the Prices. When raising Price, the Java Snippet node will increase the old Price by the ‘Price_Change_Percentage’. When lowering Price, the Java Snippet node will decrease Price towards the Cost. This ensures that Price will never dip below Marginal Cost.

The ‘Simulate Market‘ node runs a single Market Simulation for each Price Experiment. The expected results for each Competitor are then collected together for comparison.

Note that the Bertrand Paradox was also explored in another Market Simulation:

In that Building Blocks Market Simulation, two ‘Profit Engine‘ nodes were used instead of five ‘Simulate Market‘ nodes. The two ‘Profit Engine’ nodes generated ‘Demand Curves’ to calculate the ‘Profit Maximizing Price’ for each Competitor.

Increase Test Price

Market Simulation Result

Step 4: Compare Results

The three Price Experiments relevant to Spacely Sprockets are:

  1. Raise Spacely’s Price
  2. No Price Change
  3. Lower Spacely’s Price

Similarly, the three Price Experiments relevant to Cogswell Cogs are:

  1. Raise Cogswell’s Price
  2. No Price Change
  3. Lower Cogswell’s Price

The expected results for Spacely (and Cogswell) are collected together for comparison. The ‘Sorter’ node will sort the results by the Pricing Strategy that yields the greatest Profit, and the ‘Row Filter’ node will select that Pricing Strategy as the Expected Result (again assuming that the Competitor will not change Price).

The selected Price adjustments from both Competitors are then collected together and passed back to the next iteration of the Pricing Loop.

Concatenate Results

Select Profit Maximizing Price

Next Loop Iteration

Step 5: Price Trend

After the 30 iterations of the Pricing Loop, the Price Strategy trends for both Competitors can be compared and plotted.

As predicted by Joseph Bertrand, both Competitors will wish to lower Price each iteration as both expect to capture the entire Market from the other. As a result, Price trends towards Marginal Cost, and Profit trends towards zero.

Pricing Loop Results

Chart #1
Price vs Cost

Chart #2
Expected Quantity

Chart #3
Profit

Bertrand Paradox

Joseph Bertrand (1852 - 1900)

Wikipedia: The Bertrand Paradox describes a situation in which two Competitors reach a Nash equilibrium where both charge a Price equal to Marginal Cost. The paradox is that each additional Competitor is supposed to cause Prices to convergence closer to Marginal Costs until eventually Perfect Competition is reached.

Suppose two Competitors sell a homogeneous commodity, each with the same cost, so that Customers choose the Product solely on the basis of Price. Demand is infinitely price-elastic because neither Competitor will set a higher Price than the other (doing so would yield the entire market to their rival). If they set the same Price, the Competitors will share the Profits.

However, if either Competitor were to lower its price, even a little, it would gain the whole market and substantially larger Profits. Since both Competitors know this, they will each try to undercut the other until the Product is selling at zero economic profit.

Reality

There are several reasons why the Bertrand Paradox is rarely seen in practice:

Capacity Constraints: Competitors often do not have enough Capacity to satisfy all demand from the entire Market. Hence Competitors seek to set Prices above Marginal Costs at the point which all of their Production Capacity is sold. See Also: MS-172 Bertrand–Edgeworth Competition which explores a Price War between Commodity Products where both Competitors have Capacity Constraints.

Search Costs: Consumers suffer Search Costs to find the full range of their options. But when Consumers are unwilling to bear these Search Costs, Price Dispersion can result such that there is variation in Prices across Competitors selling the same Product. See Also: MS-173 Bertrand Competition with Search Costs which explores another variation of Bertrand Competition. The Products in this Market are, again, undifferentiated Commodity Products, but there are Search Costs that limit Customer awareness of each Product.

Product Differentiation: If the Products are different then Customers may not switch to the Product with the lowest Price but will continue to buy those Products that yield the greatest Consumer Surplus. See Also: MS-174 Bertrand Competition with Product Differentiation which explores the limitations of Bertrand Competition when the Products are no longer Commodities but are Differentiated from one another. And See Also: BB-131 Orthogonal Competitive Loop which explores a Competitive Price War between differentiated Products.

Shipping Costs and Geographic Differentiation: If Customers have to pay different amounts for shipping or for acquiring the Product, then they will have a natural bias to buy the commodity Product that is more local to them – even if the local Product is a little more expensive. This bias will ensure that Prices never decline down as far as Marginal Cost and that Competitors can be Profitable. See Also: CS-102 Rise of the Microbrew – Part 02 Local Monopoly which shows how Geographic Differentiation can be a source of Market Power.